Sunday, 29 Jun 2025
  • Contact
  • Privacy Policy
  • Terms & Conditions
  • DMCA
logo logo
  • World
  • Politics
  • Crime
  • Economy
  • Tech & Science
  • Sports
  • Entertainment
  • More
    • Education
    • Celebrities
    • Culture and Arts
    • Environment
    • Health and Wellness
    • Lifestyle
  • đŸ”„
  • Trump
  • House
  • VIDEO
  • White
  • ScienceAlert
  • Watch
  • Trumps
  • man
  • Health
  • Day
Font ResizerAa
American FocusAmerican Focus
Search
  • World
  • Politics
  • Crime
  • Economy
  • Tech & Science
  • Sports
  • Entertainment
  • More
    • Education
    • Celebrities
    • Culture and Arts
    • Environment
    • Health and Wellness
    • Lifestyle
Follow US
© 2024 americanfocus.online – All Rights Reserved.
American Focus > Blog > Economy > Law, Legislation, and Libertarianism – Econlib
Economy

Law, Legislation, and Libertarianism – Econlib

Last updated: May 5, 2025 7:35 am
Share
Law, Legislation, and Libertarianism – Econlib
SHARE

  • A Review of Common Law Liberalism: A New Theory of the Libertarian Society, by John Hasnas.

“Look around,” might sound like the opening line of a philosophical journey, yet John Hasnas’s insightful book, Common Law Liberalism, serves as a stark reminder against the “inattentional blindness” that often plagues social scientists, especially those who prefer theoretical musings over practical realities. Inattentional blindness refers to our tendency to overlook something glaringly obvious—like a gorilla in a room—because we are too focused on another task. In Hasnas’s narrative, that ‘gorilla’ is the law itself.

Hasnas introduces the concept of inattentional blindness to critique the market failure argument, which suggests that government intervention is essential to rectify the market’s negligence towards social costs in private transactions. While this view is widely accepted among economists, they might be indulging in an overly idealistic vision of the market as a realm of unregulated voluntary exchanges. In contrast, law is often regarded merely as a set of governmental norms designed to mitigate the fallout of these interactions.

However, both definitions fall short. The law is not limited to legislation, which is merely the product of lawmakers’ intentions. In reality, numerous norms that underpin our daily interactions stem from the “old” common law—rules derived from historical case resolutions and customary practices.

Moreover, Hasnas contends that the notion of a “realm of unregulated voluntary transactions” is a theoretical illusion. Human actions are perpetually influenced by “ethics, custom, and common law,” which are emergent orders formed through human interactions without direct oversight from any specific authority. The simplified economic model of a free market inaccurately presents a landscape devoid of regulations, when in fact, it merely illustrates a scenario prior to governmental intervention.

According to Hasnas, beliefs and customary practices evolve through trial and error, aiming to mitigate harm to others. He argues that common law civil liability developed to address actions causing harm that existing laws failed to prevent. Contrary to the belief that civil liability is weak or irrelevant, he asserts that the evidence indicates it may be excessively punitive. A prime example is the infamous 1994 McDonald’s coffee cup lawsuit.

In this case, a 79-year-old woman, while attempting to add cream and sugar to her coffee in a parked car, spilled scalding coffee on herself, resulting in severe burns. McDonald’s corporate policy at the time required coffee to be served at a temperature of 180 to 190 degrees Fahrenheit. The woman was awarded $640,000 in damages, leading McDonald’s to lower its coffee temperature to 158 degrees. This case is often cited as evidence that civil liability imposes overly stringent safety regulations. Hasnas, however, points out that this example merely illustrates civil liability as an alternative to regulatory measures. He contrasts this with the BP oil spill incident, where it was the lack of civil liability that necessitated regulatory intervention to curb risky drilling practices.

“A free market economy had indeed been rejected by the 20th century. Yet wasn’t it at least centered on some rules, which by definition limited the discretion of rulers?”

After a period of decline in classical liberalism throughout the first half of the 20th century, its resurgence post-World War II reignited discussions about the rule of law as a fundamental component of classical liberal thought. Some trace this revival to the formation of the Mont Pelerin Society in 1947, while others point to landmark publications in the early 1960s, such as F.A. Hayek’s The Constitution of Liberty and Milton Friedman’s Capitalism and Freedom. These theorists posited that the rule of law could provide a pathway out of authoritarianism, thereby restoring some credibility to market economies. While the 20th century largely rejected the notion of a free market, it at least acknowledged the need for rules that limit arbitrary power—rules that are arguably more favorable than the whims of an unchecked bureaucracy.

Yet, Hasnas warns against a blanket endorsement of “rules.” His writing echoes the arguments of Bruno Leoni in his 1961 work, Freedom and the Law, which criticized Hayek’s perspectives. Leoni highlighted the stark differences between British common law and the European Rechtsstaat, emphasizing how each fosters different interpretations of the rule of law. He argued that while written laws might suggest certainty, they can be altered at the discretion of legislative bodies, often resulting in unpredictable outcomes. Hasnas provocatively asks: how many among us truly read and understand the laws that govern us, especially as legislation proliferates weekly?

Hasnas draws a distinction between “political” and “nonpolitical” law. Nonpolitical law evolves organically, without centralized control, while political law is shaped by deliberate human efforts directed towards specific ends.

Despite the prevailing political culture that favors political law, Hasnas challenges the assumption that law should inherently pursue the common good or be rooted in a consensus from democratic assemblies. He posits that many legal norms, arising from political processes, often serve the interests of select groups rather than the broader society.

Legal norms, he suggests, should serve as mechanisms for resolving conflicts peacefully, rather than as tools for enforcing a theoretical ideal of justice. He recounts the historical shift in England post-Roman Empire, where rules naturally developed to promote peaceful coexistence. The transition from blood feuds—where retribution was the expected response—to negotiated settlements illustrates how societies have historically sought to avoid violence through compromise. Such negotiations often involved compensatory payments, leading to the establishment of customary laws that outlined community members’ obligations toward one another. In this context, rights become “problems solved,” representing efforts to calibrate appropriate compensations for various transgressions.

Hasnas likens customary law to a communication system that facilitates social coordination, akin to how price mechanisms function in economics. This raises a vital question: isn’t law, in all its forms, a means to achieve order, regardless of its origins? Hasnas doesn’t assert that customary or common law is infallible; he acknowledges the potential for “legal failure” in systems lacking centralized planning. Nevertheless, he argues that political legal systems often fail to produce “rules of just conduct”—universal principles that do not cater to specific interests. Entrusting law-making to particular individuals or groups tends to skew the resulting norms to benefit certain factions over others.

For further insights on these topics, see

Many may accept this imbalance as a necessary compromise. After all, a society devoid of laws is often considered ungovernable. However, Hasnas prompts us to reconsider this belief, drawing on historical examples from early Medieval England, the Law Merchant, and contemporary international arbitration systems. He highlights the numerous interactions in our daily lives governed by norms that are not the result of formal legislation. Indeed: look around.

See also  Law firms face backlash over deals with Trump as judge blocks Perkins Coie order
TAGGED:EconliblawLegislationLibertarianism
Share This Article
Twitter Email Copy Link Print
Previous Article 65-year-old man found shot on West Side street, but nobody called 911 to report gunfire 65-year-old man found shot on West Side street, but nobody called 911 to report gunfire
Next Article A$AP Rocky, Serena Williams, Rihanna Attend Anna Wintour Pre-Met Gala Dinner A$AP Rocky, Serena Williams, Rihanna Attend Anna Wintour Pre-Met Gala Dinner
Leave a comment

Leave a Reply Cancel reply

Your email address will not be published. Required fields are marked *

Popular Posts

Top HHS spokesman abruptly quits after reports of tensions with RFK Jr., his team

Thomas Corry, the former top spokesman at the Department of Health and Human Services, made…

March 3, 2025

MSNBC Host Puts Trump Adviser ‘On Notice’ Over ‘False Quote’

During a live interview on MSNBC, host Ari Melber confronted Trump campaign senior adviser Corey…

August 29, 2024

Dax Shepard Loved Wife Kristen Bell ‘Hot’ Rom-Com Kiss With Adam Brody

Kristen Bell's husband, Dax Shepard, is quite impressed by the chemistry she shares with Adam…

October 4, 2024

Your gaming PC is overdue for an upgrade—Windows 11 Pro can fix that

Are you still using Windows 10 on your gaming PC? If so, it's time to…

May 15, 2025

Trump Comes To Western Pennsylvania To Tell Steelworkers That He Is Killing Their Jobs By Doubling Tariffs

PoliticusUSA relies on the support of readers like you. Please consider helping us by becoming…

May 30, 2025

You Might Also Like

Elon Musk Goes Off On President Trump’s “Big, Beautiful Bill” After Senate Makes a Significant Change to the Legislation |
Politics

Elon Musk Goes Off On President Trump’s “Big, Beautiful Bill” After Senate Makes a Significant Change to the Legislation |

June 29, 2025
My Weekly Reading for June 29, 2025
Economy

My Weekly Reading for June 29, 2025

June 29, 2025
Iran could restart enriching uranium in months, says nuclear watchdog head
Economy

Iran could restart enriching uranium in months, says nuclear watchdog head

June 29, 2025
3 No-Brainer Warren Buffett Stocks to Buy Right Now
Economy

3 No-Brainer Warren Buffett Stocks to Buy Right Now

June 29, 2025
logo logo
Facebook Twitter Youtube

About US


Explore global affairs, political insights, and linguistic origins. Stay informed with our comprehensive coverage of world news, politics, and Lifestyle.

Top Categories
  • Crime
  • Environment
  • Sports
  • Tech and Science
Usefull Links
  • Contact
  • Privacy Policy
  • Terms & Conditions
  • DMCA

© 2024 americanfocus.online –  All Rights Reserved.

Welcome Back!

Sign in to your account

Lost your password?