Understanding the Chaotic Tariff Moves of President Trump
What lies behind President Donald Trump’s erratic approach to tariffs? On April 9, just after the implementation of his “reciprocal tariffs” and amid unsettling signs in financial markets, including Treasury bonds, he declared a 90-day suspension for most tariffs exceeding 10%. His reasoning? People were “getting … a little bit afraid.” “I thought that people were jumping a little bit out of line. They were getting yippy.” Ultimately, he claimed the pause “was written from the heart.” Interestingly, this echoes sentiments from Nicolás Maduro, Venezuela’s beleaguered leader, who also asserted, “I act out of love.”
The Absence of a Grand Strategy?
If Trump’s seemingly nonsensical behavior isn’t rooted in a sincere affection for the American people, might there be some hidden grand strategy at play? Financial Times columnist Janan Ganesh argues otherwise, suggesting that Trump’s actions stem from sheer irrationality. He points out that Trump juggles the MAGA ambition of containing China with the “Liberation Day” aim of imposing tariffs on imports from allied nations. Ganesh concludes:
Ultimately, the contradictions within Trump’s worldview are too numerous to support any claims of a grand strategy. If strategy implies understanding the interconnectedness of things, that awareness is notably absent here.
A Rational Choice Approach
While such a hypothesis can be tempting, it tends to explain everything and its opposite. A more grounded approach for an economist is to consider a rational choice framework, albeit with some necessary caveats. Like any individual, Trump’s primary objective is to advance his own interests. This motivation is intensified in the political arena, where his desire for recognition and insatiable appetite for power dominate. Nevertheless, his chosen methods often contradict these objectives, suggesting a failure in his instrumental rationality. This inconsistency likely arises from a profound lack of understanding of societal mechanics—knowledge that is essential in economics. Should he somehow become a lifetime president, I may need to reassess my theory of instrumental rationality, and Ganesh might have to concede that Trump indeed had a clever plan all along.
The Nature of Political Mistakes
Individuals typically learn from their mistakes in personal affairs, but those at the pinnacle of power face a different reality. When a leader errs, the repercussions predominantly affect others, thereby diminishing their incentives to rectify their missteps. The greater the power, the more costly mistakes they believe they can afford—or so they think.
Self-Interest Behind State Actions
In many cases, the grand designs of governments merely reflect the self-interest of their leaders. This self-interest often requires rewarding influential backers—typically lobbyists and political donors—resulting in policies that may appear disjointed. Moreover, populist leaders often rely on instinctive decision-making, as Trump indicated when he exempted certain electronics from tariffs. After all, a populist knows the “truth” in their gut, which supposedly embodies “the people.” So much for the notion of rational state planning. Just a day after announcing the temporary tariff suspension, Trump hinted that it might not last long anyway.
A Comedy of Tariff Policies
As one businessman and investor humorously remarked, “This is starting to look more like stand-up comedy than ‘tariff policy.’”
The Misunderstanding of Tariffs
Trump’s trade maneuvers, which he frames as “deals” for “his” constituents, reveal a fundamental misunderstanding of economic principles and the ethical considerations necessary for a functioning free society. Imposing tariffs on another nation effectively translates into a tax on one’s own citizens. When Trump insists, “What they charge us, we charge them,” he is, in essence, declaring, “What they impose on their citizens, I impose on mine.” It’s an unsettling realization that he seems to grasp when he makes exemptions. The moral quandary here is akin to a kidnapper offering a deal after the abduction—he demands a ransom for your freedom. This “art of the deal” is reminiscent of coercion by unchecked powers against their citizens, foreigners, or both.
The Voter’s Dilemma
Why do voters often overlook these inconsistencies or take so long to recognize them? A significant explanation lies in public choice theory, which highlights “rational ignorance.” Since an individual voter has negligible influence over election outcomes, they lack the incentive to invest time and resources in understanding complex political issues.
The Role of Strong Institutions
The libertarian and classical liberal ideal seeks to limit the power of rulers to prevent harm. The resilience we’ve seen in many Western countries over the past few centuries can be attributed to robust institutions—both sets of rules and influential counterbalancing entities—that promote the decentralization of power. A prevailing belief in personal liberty has historically protected society, albeit imperfectly, from the whims of populist leaders and their demagogic tendencies.