While Paris remains picturesque and well-fed, our economy is navigating choppy waters, and the reasons behind this turbulence are manifold. A point worth emphasizing is the frequent oversight by many economists regarding the significance of systems thinking and its practical applications.
So, what exactly is systems thinking? At its core, it involves examining a complete framework—where “system” denotes an institutional structure and the myriad individual actions occurring within it. This approach can also be utilized to compare various systems, though it’s important to note that the institutional framework often garners the most scrutiny. A classic illustration of systems thinking can be found in the analysis of planned versus market economies, a debate that preoccupied economists during the first half of the 20th century. This ideological clash is evident in the socialist calculation debate, where differing economists reached diverse conclusions about the efficacy of the systems they scrutinized.
In contrast to systems thinking is the tendency to analyze specific issues as isolated incidents. The aim here is not to elucidate how an entire system operates but rather to tackle pressing individual problems in search of optimal solutions. Take, for instance, the housing crisis: a focused analysis might diagnose a scarcity of housing availability, attributing it to stringent zoning laws and enduring rent control policies. Recommendations may range from modifying zoning regulations to eliminating price controls and boosting subsidized housing initiatives. Nevertheless, this approach remains confined to the specific issue at hand, neglecting the broader context.
Today, as Randall Holcombe points out, “economists no longer engage with economic systems in the twenty-first century as they did in the twentieth.” In simpler terms, economists have shifted their focus from systems thinking to addressing issues within market frameworks, primarily formulating recommendations to tackle specific problems. They accept the existing (and often flawed) market system as a given, analyzing its components and suggesting improvements typically through government intervention—whether that involves altering existing policies, introducing new ones, or lifting outdated regulations.
This narrow focus is perilous, primarily because it obscures the larger picture. There are two interconnected risks here. First, economists may inadvertently create a new system that yields unfavorable outcomes due to the unintended consequences of their recommendations. In essence, governmental actions can fundamentally alter the nature of the economic system, leading it far from the ideal envisioned by the economist. However, because they have not engaged in systems thinking, they may overlook this systemic risk.
Secondly, the economist may possess a limited understanding of the stability of the system taken for granted, which is directly influenced by their proposals. There is a monumental distinction between dismissing a particular policy approach and rejecting the concept of public policy itself. A systems analysis could reveal that the very public policies favored by most economists are likely to be implemented in ways they do not endorse. In other words, the nature of public policy is inherently tied to the system’s framework. To discern this, a holistic examination of the entire system is often necessary, rather than a piecemeal analysis of isolated interventions. Economists may remain blissfully unaware that their suggestions could be contributing to the economic miscalculations they lament. This echoes Michael Munger’s sage advice: do not craft a weapon so formidable that it becomes a threat in the hands of your adversaries.
Thus, what economists must contemplate is the broader implications of public policy interventions. They need to reconnect with systems thinking and the comparative analysis of various economic frameworks. Randall Holcombe’s insights, particularly in his work on Political Capitalism, serve as an excellent starting point for this essential shift.
Max Molden is a PhD student at the University of Hamburg. He has collaborated with European Students for Liberty and Prometheus – Das Freiheitsinstitut. His work frequently appears in Der Freydenker.