The proposal to have the Federal Reserve subsidize an NGDP futures market, as suggested by economist Scott Sumner, presents several challenges that need to be carefully considered. One of the main concerns is the potential for market manipulation and distorted incentives that could arise from such a system. The idea behind using a market for NGDP futures as a feedback loop into monetary policy is theoretically sound, but in practice, there are several issues that could undermine its effectiveness.
Market manipulation is a significant risk with this proposal. If the Fed is expected to adjust monetary policy based on the NGDP futures price, traders may have strong incentives to manipulate the market in their favor. This could lead to coordinated efforts to move the futures price in a direction that benefits their portfolios, potentially influencing the central bank’s policy decisions. The subsidization of the market could make it more vulnerable to such manipulation, as it lowers the cost for traders with non-informational motives to exploit the system.
Another concern is the potential for information asymmetry and noise trading in the NGDP futures market. The presence of a subsidy could attract traders who are more focused on exploiting the subsidy or the Fed’s reaction function rather than making informed decisions based on economic fundamentals. This could result in a market that is less reflective of genuine expectations about future economic conditions and more driven by speculators trying to game the system.
To address these challenges, Scott Sumner proposes an alternative approach called the “guardrails approach” to NGDP futures targeting. This approach involves the Fed announcing a willingness to take unlimited long positions on NGDP futures contracts based on a specific growth rate and unlimited short positions based on another growth rate. This strategy allows the Fed to profit when the actual growth rate falls within the specified range, without the need for market manipulation or subsidy.
Critics may question the effectiveness of this approach, particularly in scenarios where trading activity is low or when policy is off course. However, Sumner argues that the guardrails approach leverages the “wisdom of crowds” to guide the Fed’s policy decisions. By setting clear constraints on policy and aligning market expectations with the desired outcomes, the Fed can ensure that its monetary policy remains credible and responsive to changing economic conditions.
Overall, the guardrails approach to NGDP futures targeting offers a practical and transparent mechanism for influencing monetary policy without the risks associated with market manipulation. By incorporating market signals into its decision-making process, the Fed can benefit from the collective wisdom of traders and maintain credibility in its policy actions.
In conclusion, the guardrails approach to NGDP futures targeting presents a viable alternative to the traditional subsidy model, offering a more sustainable and effective way to incorporate market feedback into monetary policy decisions. By focusing on credibility and market-driven constraints, this approach can help the Fed navigate complex economic environments and ensure that its policies are aligned with the broader goals of economic stability and growth.