At the beginning of this week, I presented a conundrum involving price theory.
Imagine the government enacting a strict price ceiling on oranges while leaving orange juice free from similar restrictions. Following the introduction of this ceiling on oranges, what implications will it have on the pricing of orange juice? (Assuming a competitive market for oranges.) Please illustrate your reasoning.
I promised to share my response, along with a diagram depicting the demand and supply dynamics. However, plotting this out became quite complex due to the interconnected demand and supply for both oranges and orange juice. Oranges serve dual purposes: they are vital as an ingredient for orange juice and are also sold directly to consumers as fresh fruit.
Fortunately, to derive the answer, one needn’t delve into the intricate demand and supply for orange juice. The key insight is that a binding price ceiling on oranges will lead to a reduction in the quantity of oranges produced. This core change is what drives the subsequent outcomes. While one could depict this adjustment on a supply and demand curve for oranges, it’s not strictly necessary. (I had my students create these diagrams, as a learning exercise.)
In my years teaching the economics surrounding binding price controls—be it ceilings or floors—I’ve often stated, “the short side of the market prevails.” In the case of a price ceiling, the market’s supply diminishes, resulting in fewer goods available for purchase. Conversely, with a price floor, demand takes precedence, leading to unsold goods as buyers withdraw. In essence, the dynamics of supply and demand dictate market realities.
Returning to our scenario: as the output of oranges decreases, the supply of orange juice will also decline. Assuming demand for orange juice remains steady (though a potential increase in demand could occur if consumers pivot towards orange juice due to the scarcity of oranges, complicating matters), the unchanged demand alongside reduced supply will compel the price of orange juice to rise. Thus, we reach our conclusion.
One commenter raised pertinent inquiries regarding the extent of the price increase for orange juice, which are indeed significant but do not affect the fundamental premise of a price rise.
AMW commented:
Is this scenario set in an open or closed economy? Can oranges and orange juice be imported or exported? And how elastic are the international supply and demand for these products?
All these considerations are crucial for estimating the magnitude of the price increase. For instance, if orange producers choose to export their goods to sidestep domestic price regulations, it would further tighten the available domestic supply, consequently amplifying the price rise for orange juice.
Henri Hein succinctly echoed this sentiment:
I align with Jon Murphy on this: with a price ceiling on oranges, the supply of oranges will decline. Assuming the demand for orange juice remains constant (at the pre-change price), the price of orange juice will inevitably increase.
Postscript:
To conceptualize this dilemma, consider the automobile market in 1946 when the U.S. government began permitting domestic car manufacturers to resume production for local consumers. Whether due to producers’ hesitance to raise prices or because of existing price controls—details I cannot recall—the result was a market where new car prices did not align with supply and demand. Consequently, buyers would purchase cars only to “flip” them at a premium shortly after. Think of orange juice producers engaging in a similar “flipping” of oranges.