The sun rises over Tokyo, casting a warm glow as you sit on your balcony with your favorite morning beverage. Birds chirp in a serene symphony of dawnâuntil the tranquility is upended by a colossal, radioactive kaiju known as Godzilla.
In sheer disbelief, you watch as the towering, glowing creature emerges from the waters, embarking on a destructive path across the city, crumbling buildings and wreaking havoc in its wake. Amidst the escalating chaos, a bizarre thought crosses your mind: At least the construction companies in Tokyo will have plenty of work. There must be a silver lining to all this, right?
Frédéric Bastiat would likely have a few insights to share.
Bastiat, an influential French economist and writer of the 19th century, is perhaps best remembered for his essay “What Is Seen and What Is Not Seen” (part of Economic Sophisms), where he introduced what is commonly referred to as the broken window fallacy. In this work, Bastiat highlights how economic assessments tend to concentrate on immediate observable effectsâwhat is âseenââwhile neglecting opportunity costs and long-term repercussionsâwhat is ânot seen.â
In his well-known illustration, Mr. Goodfellow and his son walk by a store and accidentally shatter its window. The storeowner then hires a glazier to replace it, leading Goodfellow to argue that this is beneficial for the economy, as it creates work for the glazier. However, Bastiat contests this logic: while the glazier earns money, the shopkeeper loses the opportunity to spend that same money in a different wayâsay, by purchasing new shoes or investing back into his business. Instead of stimulating growth, the economy merely reallocates resources without creating additional wealth.
Now, letâs extend Mr. Goodfellowâs reasoning: if shattering a window benefits economic activity, couldnât torching an entire city yield even more construction jobs?
This brings us to our friend, Godzilla.
As Godzilla rampages through Tokyo, obliterating homes, offices, retail spaces, and factories, Bastiat would frown at anyone suggesting that Japanâs construction sector, or the nation altogether, stands to gain from the destruction. The chaos may generate economic activity, but itâs hardly productive. The rebuild wonât increase wealth; it merely tries to replace what has been wrecked.
The expenses would be staggering: in currency and in human cost. Lives would be lost, injuries would abound, and vital infrastructure would be dismantled. The nuclear fallout from Godzillaâs presence would necessitate extensive environmental remediation. Defense budgets would swell as Japanâand potentially other nationsâgear up for future kaiju confrontations. All these facets would be âseenâ: construction bids issued, cleanup teams mobilized, relief services bolstered.
However, Bastiat would urge us to examine the aspects that are not apparent: the missed alternatives. Taxpayer funds allocated for rebuilding could have facilitated improvements in infrastructure, advancements in education, scientific exploration, or tax reductions. The human capital obliterated in the disaster is irreplaceable. Trade could also suffer, as international companies reevaluate their dealings with a nation prone to such unpredictable leviathan threats. While global allies may offer assistanceâa noble ideaâthis too would redirect resources toward remedial efforts rather than fostering true wealth.
Ultimately, the Godzilla scenario presents a significant economic setback rather than an opportunity. The fallacy lies in equating frantic reconstruction with genuine growth. This misconception persists today, particularly in discussions of spending in the wake of disasters. Just because expenditures are made does not imply that wealth is generated.
As echoes of Mr. Goodfellowâs simplistic optimism linger through time, Bastiatâs teachings remind us to delve deeper into economic realities. Even a monstrous radioactive kaiju cannot escape the fundamental truths about economics that Bastiat illuminated nearly two centuries ago.
Ethan Kelley is a Legislative Analyst for the Knee Regulatory Research Center at West Virginia University.
RECENT POST
The sun rises over Tokyo, casting a warm glow as you sit on your balcony with your favorite morning beverage. Birds chirp in a serene symphony of dawnâuntil the tranquility is upended by a colossal, radioactive kaiju known as Godzilla.
In sheer disbelief, you watch as the towering, glowing creature emerges from the waters, embarking on a destructive path across the city, crumbling buildings and wreaking havoc in its wake. Amidst the escalating chaos…
Despite average home prices remaining near all-time highs, public opinion is increasingly concerned about housing affordability, prompting politicians to take action. The Trump administration has joined the conversation, hinting at upcoming national housing initiatives designed to address these challenges…
Recently, the Trump Administration announced a new $100,000 fee for H-1B applications, on top of existing fees and legal expenses. The H-1B visa enables companies to recruit foreign individuals possessing a college degree for specialized positions. Firms must enter a lottery system, and if selected, they can submit their applications…